Meran, Georg and von Hirschhausen, Christian, Increasing Block Tariffs in the Water Sector: An Interpretation in Terms of Social Preferences (September 2014). DIW Berlin Discussion Paper No. 1434. Available at SSRN:http://ssrn.com/abstract=2553084 or http://dx.doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.2553084
Abstract
Many developing countries around the world apply progressive water tariffs, often structured in the form of discretely increasing block tariffs (IBTs). These tariffs have been criticized in the welfare economic literature due to their perceived inefficiency: many of the prices charged under IBTs do not correspond to marginal costs and thus violate the principle of allocative efficiency. In this paper we explore an alternative interpretation of the widespread use of IBTs, in terms of social preferences and fairness considerations. For this, we rely on an extension of the Fehr and Schmidt (1999) utility function, including inequality aversion, to which we add another parameter representing a preference for redistribution, which reflects a societal preference to correct for income difference perceived as unfair. In addition, the paper also includes household size in the analysis, finding that as poor households are on average larger (in per capita terms), a simple IBT tariff disregarding household size may not be "fair" at all. We conclude on a methodological note on the importance of addressing allocative and distributional issues simultaneously.
Among the challenges facing the world, perhaps none is more important than ensuring adequate supplies of clean water for all the many needs and purposes people have. In many developing countries, the consequences of the lack of these most basic services impacts mortality, especially children mortality, health, education opportunities, and social development. This blog discusses these problems to increase awareness and motivate each one to become an active part of the solutions.
Feb 20, 2015
The Benefits Of Reusing Wastewater
Only
2.5 percent of the world's water is fresh water, and of that, only 1 percent is
accessible as much is trapped in glaciers and snowfields. As a result, only a
tiny fraction of the planet's water is available for everyday use. By one
estimate, global fresh water demand will exceed supply by a staggering 40
percent in 2030 if current trends continue.
As corporate citizens, businesses must look at their impact on the environment and assess how their operations affect the communities they operate in and serve. By reducing their source water requirements, food and beverage companies of any size can do their part to reduce environmental impact, while reinforcing their corporate social responsibility. Many companies also realize substantial cost savings from water-related investments.
As corporate citizens, businesses must look at their impact on the environment and assess how their operations affect the communities they operate in and serve. By reducing their source water requirements, food and beverage companies of any size can do their part to reduce environmental impact, while reinforcing their corporate social responsibility. Many companies also realize substantial cost savings from water-related investments.
Jan 5, 2015
Integrated Water Resources Management and its Contribution Towards Achieving the MDGs
The interface of water resources and development and
the achievement of the MDGs is complex and includes many specific
linkages. Examples of the linkages
between water and achieving the MDGs are emphasized in the previous section. This wide array of important linkages that
present many synergies, explains why pursuing each
goal separately reduces the complex process of human and economic development
to a series of conflicting, and unsustainable interventions. In addition, the interface of water
resources and the achievement of the MDGs occurs at
several different institutional levels, explaining why water resource policies
in many countries have evolved in a fragmented and piecemeal fashion. Under this framework, policy objectives have
been set without consideration of the implications for other water users and
without consultation across sectoral and institutional boundaries. This traditional approach to water management
has, in general, proven to be an ineffective policy strategy due to the fact
that these problems fall outside of the normal purview of the agencies tasked
with addressing them and, thus, require cooperation from multiple sectors. In order to optimize water resources
for development and the MDGs, countries must overcome constraints through
appropriate investments and management arrangements within broad planning and
policy iniciatives.
Saleth and Dinar (1999, 2004) also emphasize that
institutional changes are needed to improve water management since previous
institutions were developed during a water surplus era. Moreover, as Global Water Partnership (2000) points
out, water management is usually left to top-down institutions, the legitimacy
and effectiveness of which have increasingly been questioned. However, it is
important to highlight that the effectiveness of these sectoral improvements
will be affected by the country’s institutional and macroeconomic environment since many of these
reforms depend on economic, ecological, and political constraints (Saleth and
Dinar, 2004) and reflect the fact that institutional reform is path dependent
(North, 1990).
An IWRM approach, defined as a process
that “promotes the coordinated development and management of water, land, and
related resources, in order to maximize the resultant economic and social
welfare in an equitable manner without compromising the sustainability of vital
ecosystems” (Global Water Partnership website), provides an opportunity to
attack these problems more effectively, identifying root causes and solutions
that lie outside of any one specific sectoral area and focusing on investment
as well as management issues. IWRM is not a reform whose objective is just to
achieve a more efficient management of water as a resource, it considers
reforms whose objectives are to improve governance and financial systems at all
levels, in order to meet each country’s development goals.
Thus, an IWRM approach considers the
diverse linkages between water resources and the achievement of the MDGs, ensuring that investments across sectors work together,
producing greater returns by exploiting the synergies between the
linkages. In addition, the involvement
of multiple sectors highlights opportunities that are often hidden by sectoral
thinking. For example, examining domestic water and sanitation needs along with
food security issues generates opportunities to provide communities with water
for domestic and food production purposes at a lower additional cost compared
with traditional water planning approaches (Global Water Partnership, 2004a). IWRM also helps reduce the negative consequences
of undesired environmental impacts associated with water development and the
costs associated to the environmental damage. For example, the annual cost of mitigating
the effects of land and water degradation in Asia
associated to water development strategies has been estimated at US$35 billion
(Global Water Partnership, 2004a). Finally, since IWRM considers in an
integrated manner social, economic and environmental goals, it promotes a more
strategic and socially efficient water allocation than traditional approaches
driven individual sectors interests. The
UN Task Force on water and sanitation, based on the advantages of IWRM,
is convinced the MDGs as a whole will not be met unless an IWRM Plan, which
considers deliberate planning and investment in sound water resources
management and infrastructure, is implemented (Lenton, 2005).
1. Saleth, R.M. and Dinar, A. 1999. Evaluating water
institutions and water sector performance Tech.
paper 447, World Bank, Washington D.C.
Available at: http://www-wds.worldbank.org/external/default/WDSContentServer/IW3P/IB/1999/09/21/000094946_99090305381648/Rendered/PDF/multi_page.pdf
2.
Saleth, R.M. and Dinar, A. 2004. The institutional economics of water: A cross country analysis of
institutions and performance Edward Elgar, Mass. 398 pp.
3. Global Water Partnership. 2004a. Catalyzing Change: A Handbook for Developing
Integrated Water Resources Management (IWRM) and Water Efficiency Strategies.
Technical Advisory Committee, Global Water Partnership, Stockholm , Sweden . www.gwpforum.org
4. Lenton, R. 2005. Water Resources Management and the
Millenium Development Goals. Presentation at the Seminar Water and the
Millenium Development Goals: It’s Contribution to Development. Organized by
IDB. Okinawa , Japan , April 6, 2005.
Environmental Sustainability and #Water
Reduced water quantity and quality have serious negative impacts on
ecosystems. The environment has a natural absorptive, self-cleansing capacity;
however, if this is exceeded, biodiversity is lost, livelihoods are affected,
natural food sources are damaged and high clean-up costs result. Unesco (2003) points
out that increased environmental damage has led to a greater occurrence of natural
disasters, such as floods where deforestation and soil erosion have prevented natural
water attenuation. More specifically, between 1991 and 2000 over 665,000 people
died in 2,557 natural disasters— 90% of which were water-related and 97% of the
victims were from developing countries. Based
on this marked increase, Hideaki (2005) proposes that the target to halve human
loss due to water disasters by 2015 be added to the MDGs.
Additionally, unsustainable agricultural activities such as the draining
of wetlands for agriculture and land clearance, among others, lead to significant
negative impacts on the future availability of water (Unesco, 2003). The
reduction and degradation of natural water courses due to deforestation and
over-extraction of water have put many wetlands and marine ecosystems at risk. Therefore, ecosystem health, in turn, is
critical to the quantity and quality of freshwater supply and, thus, sustainable
water resources management requires ecosystem-based management. IWRM Plans do not regard the ecosystem as a
user of water in competition with other users, but as the base from which the
resource is derived and upon which development is planned (Jewitt, 2001).
#Water is required to achieve MDG 5. Improve Maternal Health
Access to adequate water
in quantity and quality affects maternal health by reducing labor burdens and health problems resulting from water portage;
improving nutrition which reduces the susceptibility to anemia and other
conditions that affect maternal mortality; and malaria is particularly
dangerous to pregnant women, and better water management reduces mosquito
habitats. Thus water available to women
affect their health and maternal health problems impacts and prevent the proper
care of children, undermining development efforts. Additionally, educated women with access to
adequate resources are better able to care for themselves. Thus, meeting the
MDGs for education and women’s empowerment by improving the management of water
has a positive impact on maternal health
Most water related diseases effects impact negatively maternal health and, thus, must be considered as an integral part of the necessary strategies in order to achieve this goal
Most water related diseases effects impact negatively maternal health and, thus, must be considered as an integral part of the necessary strategies in order to achieve this goal
Increasing access to safe water and thereby reducing child mortality
While most countries are committed to increasing
access to safe water and thereby reducing child mortality, there is little
consensus on how to actually increase access to safe water and sanitation
coverage and to improve water service. Some
developing countries have implemented a strategy based on the privatization of
water provision companies. Galiani,
Gertler, and Schargrodsky (2005), using the variation in ownership of water
provision across time and space generated by the privatization process in
Argentina, found that child mortality fell 8 percent in the areas that
privatized their water services; and that the effect was largest (26 percent)
in the poorest areas.
Galiani, S., Gertler, P., and Schargrodsky, E. 2005. Water for Life: The Impact of the Privatization of Water Services on Child Mortality. Journal of Political Economy, 113 (1), 83-120
Galiani, S., Gertler, P., and Schargrodsky, E. 2005. Water for Life: The Impact of the Privatization of Water Services on Child Mortality. Journal of Political Economy, 113 (1), 83-120
Dec 18, 2014
Urban Water and Sanitation Sector in Chile
During the 1980s, the sector
was dominated by governmental water-supply utilities, which supplied water and
sanitation (WSS) services to most of Chile.
The inclusion of private operators began in 1988. The urban water supply coverage in 1993 was
97.6%, and the service was provided mainly by state owned water supply
operators (see Figure 1). Furthermore,
only 85.9% of urban population had access to sewer collection and only 13% of
wastewater was treated. The driver of this situation was the low investment in
infrastructure; the estimated investment cost deficit for the 1993 – 2000
period was $2.4 billion. A 63% of the deficit
was in wastewater treatment. Before
1993, the average annual investment of the state owned operators was $150
million.
Figure 1: Growth and Evolution
Regulated Water and Sanitation Sector (Own elaboration based on SISS, 2013)
During 1994, several of the 13 state
owned WSS operators presented losses; for example Essat presented -4.1% and
Emssa -3.2%. This was, in part due to a
30% increase in average costs between 1990 y 1994. Administrative costs
increased during this period; ESVAL incremented its administrative costs in 140%
while EMOS increased by 40%. Furthermore, non-revenue water varied between 24%
and 43%.
The actual legal framework of
the WSS sector established in 1988, establishes the following objectives that water
and sanitation tariffs must satisfy:
a) Full
recovery of operation and maintenance costs;
b) Fund
necessary infrastructure reposition and development plan investment;
c) Tariff
reductions when operators increase efficiency; and
d) Operational
margins that are consistent with the opportunity cost of capital.
The legal framework of the
Chilean water and sanitation tariff system establishes that tariffs must
satisfy the principles of i) economic efficiency, ii) water conservation
incentives, iii) equity, and (v) affordabiliy (Chavez, 2002).
In order to comply with
economic efficiency, the WSS tariffs are based on a two Part Tariff, following Coase’s
Solution: a variable and fixed tariff. The variable tariff is set following Hotelling’s
Principle; thus, variable water tariff is consistent with the first best
solution where marginal benefits are equal to long-run marginal costs[1]
(MC) and social welfare is maximized (Figure 2). However, this variable tariff set at MC does
not cover the operator’s average costs; that is, the WSS providers operate with
losses. In order to satisfy the full
cost recovery principle, a fixed tariff is included so as to cover the natural
monopoly’s losses at the first best solution.
Figure 2: Tariff setting Principles
The Executive Decree 453 of the
1988 Law N° 70, of the Ministry of Public Works (Ministerio de Obras Públicas, MOP) establishes a variable tariff which
is set for periods of high demand, during summer months, (peak variable tariff
$/m3) and for non-peak periods (non-peak variable tariff $/m3).
The peak and non-peak tariffs are considered so as to internalize changes in
seasonal demand and thus cover differences in the provision costs of the service.
As previously pointed out, the current tariff structure also considers a fixed
charge per customer (connection), which depends on the diameter of the
connection.
In order to estimate the variable
charge, the Chilean tariff law introduced the concept of the incremental
development cost, which is defined as the value that applied to the incremental
forecasted demand generates the necessary revenues, so as to cover incremental
operation efficient costs and the required investment associated to an
optimized expansion project the WSS firm.
The incremental development cost is determined such that the net present
value of the optimized expansion project is equal to zero (D.F.L. No 70/1988).
The variable tariff also considers
the value of water so that consumers consider the scarcity of water in their
consumption decisions[2]. This generates correct incentives to conserve
water in resource scarce areas. For
example, average variable non-peak and peak tariffs in the Dry Pacific arid
system are $1.3/m3 and $2.2/m3. In the Southern Humid
Pacific System, on the other hand, they are $0.88/m3 and $1.3/m3,
respectively. Fixed tariffs also vary according to water scarcity representing
$1.9/m3 and $0.8/ m3 in the Dry and Southern Humid
Pacific systems, respectively (SISS, 2013).
Additionally, evidence that tariffs send the right signals to consumers
is that average monthly household consumption has significantly fallen since
1998 from approximately 25 m3/household/month to 18.6 m3/household/month
in 2013 (Figure 3).
Figure 3: Average monthly household
water consumption (m3/household/month) (SISS, 2013)
The affordability criteria is met by the provision of
subsidies directly to the most vulnerable households. Households are classified
based on an annual survey (Encuesta Casen)
which estimates household per capita income. In order to qualify for the subsidy,
households must not have payment arrears with the service provider. The central
government transfers the block subsidy to the municipalities; the latter use
this to pay a share of each of the eligible household’s water bill; the payment
share ranges from 15 to 85 per cent of the water bill, with the poorest
families getting the highest share. The subsidy covers a consumption of up to
20 m3. The Social Development Ministry (Ministerio de Desarrollo Social, MDS) uses the household survey
information for each Region of Chile to determine the size the block subsidy that
needs to be transferred to the municipalities. The WSS providers bill the
benefiting households for the net of subsidy amount, but indicating the full
consumption cost, and then charge the municipality for the subsidies granted[3].
The municipality will be charged interest for late payment, and the WSS
provider can discontinue service to benefiting households if there is
non-payment by the municipality. In 2011, 15% of WSS provider customers were benefited
(6% of total sales), at a cost of $80 million, and an average monthly subsidy
per household of $10.
In order to obtain the
necessary investment funds to improve its performance the WSS sector’s indicators,
during the period 1989-99, an institutional model was put in place where the
regulatory and supervisory functions were separated from the investment,
production and sale of service functions.
The new regulatory regime, which considered concessions to establish
build and operate water and sanitation services by private providers, led to an
increase in private participation in the provision of WSS services from 5% in
1999 to 95.5% in 2013. This process also
led to a significant increase in average annual investments from $200 million
to $500 million in 1999 and 2013, respectively (Figure 2). This is mainly due to the increased rate of
return on capital, due to increases in tariff rates. Tariff rates are
determined so that investors receive a low-risk return of at least 7% on
capital expenditures and therefore private WSS providers have the incentive to
invest in water provision, wastewater collection and treatment (Hearne and
Donoso, 2005). For example, sewage treatment coverage increased from 17% in 1999
to 99.8% in 2013 (Figure 2).
This reform period coincided
with the era of high economic growth (6.2% per year) with real incomes rising
significantly. Williams and Carriger (2006) propose that the transformation of
the WSS sector would not have been so successful without these high rates of
growth. The level of investment needed to attain this coverage could not have
been reached if the Chilean Government were responsible for investment. With
tariffs set centrally for water and sanitation, efficiency incentives exist for
the companies to increase returns on investment. This has happened and these
companies perform well on the Chilean Stock exchange (Bitran and Arellano,
2005).
Currently there are 53 water
and sanitation service providers operating in the urban areas of Chile. They
function as private companies although the state investment company, ECONSSA,
still owns a considerable number of share in most companies (Hearne and Donoso,
2005). Five of Chile's 13 regional water companies were fully privatized with
partial sale to multinationals in 1998.
The WSS providers service more
than 4.5 million clients[4],
94.4% of clients are domestic, 4.7% commercial, 0.2% industrial and 0.7% other.
Additionally, 95% of all clients have both drinking water and wastewater
connections. The other 5% have either one or the other, with most having only
drinking water connections.
The large and medium service
providers (8 of the 53) serve 84.2% of all clients. It is interesting to note
that a municipality (SRMPA of the Maipu municipality) owns one of them. Private
providers service 95.5% of all clients.
With respect to the
service quality, Figure 4 shows that costumer’s satisfaction levels since 2008
are over 99%. WSS clients were quite satisfied with the service, rating it with
a 5.3 on a scale of 1 to 7 (GWI, 2013).
Figure 5: Water
service quality (SISS, 2013)
Therefore, the new regulatory
scheme in the Chilean WSS sector has provided the right economic signals for an
efficient allocation of resources. It has also led to meeting the set goals for
service coverage. Additionally, the
transformation of the WSS sector has led to the
a) Improvement
in quality of service
b) Increase
in WSS provision coverage, despite rapidly increasing urban populations; and
c) Increase
in water conservation by customers.
In summary, Chile’s policy of providing water supply
and sanitation (WSS) services through privatized regional and local water
companies has been a notable success.
References
1 Bitran, G. and P. Arellano, 2005, Regulating
Water Services, Sending the Right Signals to Utilities in Chile, Public Policy
for the Private Sector, World Bank, Note number 286, March.2005. Available at Background
Document http://rru.worldbank.org/Documents/PublicPolicyJournal/286Bitran_Arellano.pdf.
2 Chavez, C. 2002, Public-Private Partnership And
Tariff Setting: The Case Of Chile, OECD Global Forum on Sustainable Development
Conference on Financing the Environmental Dimension of Sustainable Development,
24-26th April, OECD, Paris, http://www.oecd.org/sweden/2083795.pdf.
3 D.F.L. No 70/1988,
http://www.leychile.cl/Navegar?idNorma=4427.
4 Executive Decree 453 of the 1988 Law N° 70, of
the Ministry of Public Works, http://www.leychile.cl/Navegar?idNorma=98618.
5 GWI, 2013, Global Water Intelligence Market
Insight: Chile. Media Analytics Ltda. UK.
6 Hearne, R. and G. Donoso, 2005, Water
Institutional Reforms in Chile, Water Policy, 7 (2005), 53-69.
1
7 SISS, 2013, Informe de Gestión 2013.
http://www.siss.gob.cl/577/articles-10684_recurso_1.pdf
8 Williams,
S. and S Carriger, 2006, Water and Sustainable development: Lessons from Chile,
Global Water Partnership, Policy Brief 2, Technical Committee (TEC). Available
at www.gwpforum.org/gwp/library/policybrief2chile.pdf.
9 WRI
(World Resources Institute). 2003. Earth Trends Country Profiles. (http://earthtrends.wri.org/country_profiles/index.cfm?theme=2).
[1]
Long-term infrastructure investment costs are included in the water and
sanitation services tariff rates.
[2]
The value of water for each WSS provider is determined by market prices of
traded WUR.
[3]
This practice does not distort the price signals.
[4] A
client is determined by the property, rather than the individual, that receives
services and is billed for these (more than one person may live in the same
property, benefiting from the services).
Subscribe to:
Posts (Atom)